FREE BOOKS

Author's List




PREV.   NEXT  
|<   120   121   122   123   124   125   126   127   128   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144  
145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153   154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   168   169   >>   >|  
money. They never thought of denying that money, when properly used, was capable of bringing its employer a profit; but they emphatically asserted that the profit was due to the labour, and not to the money. Antoninus of Florence clearly realised this: 'Money is not profitable of itself alone, nor can it multiply itself, but it may become profitable through its employment by merchants';[1] and Bernardine of Sienna says: 'Money has not simply the character of money, but it has beyond this a productive character, which we commonly call capital.'[2] 'What is money,' says Brants, 'if it is not a means of exchange, of which the employment and preservation will give a profit, if he who possesses it is prudent, active, and intelligent? If this money is well employed, it will become a capital, and one may derive a profit from it; but this profit arises from the activity of him who uses it, and consequently this profit belongs to him--it is the fruit, the remuneration of his labour.... Did they (the scholastics) say that it was impossible to draw a profit from a sum of money? No; they admitted fully that one might _de pecunia lucrari_; but this _lucrum_ does not come from the _pecunia_, but from the application of labour to the sum.'[3] [Footnote 1: Quoted in Brants, _op. cit._, p. 134.] [Footnote 2: _Ibid._] [Footnote 3: Brants, _op. cit._, pp. 133-5; Nider, _De Cont. Merc._ iii. 15.] Therefore, if the borrower did not derive any profit from the loan, the sum lent had in fact been sterile, and obviously the just price of the loan was the return of the amount lent; if, on the contrary, the borrower had made a profit from it, it was the reward of his labour, and not the fruit of the loan itself. To repay more than the sum lent would therefore be to make a payment to one person for the labour of another.[1] The exaction of usury was therefore the exploitation of another man's exertion.[2] [Footnote 1: Gerson, _De Cont._, iv. 15.] [Footnote 2: Neumann, when he says that 'it was sinful to recompense the use of capital belonging to another' (_Geschichte des Wuchers in Deutschland_, p. 25), seems to miss the whole point of the discussion. The teaching of the canonists on rents and partnership shows clearly that the owner of capital might draw a profit from another's labour, and the central point of the usury teaching was that money which has been lent, and employed so as to produce a profit by the borrower, belongs no
PREV.   NEXT  
|<   120   121   122   123   124   125   126   127   128   129   130   131   132   133   134   135   136   137   138   139   140   141   142   143   144  
145   146   147   148   149   150   151   152   153   154   155   156   157   158   159   160   161   162   163   164   165   166   167   168   169   >>   >|  



Top keywords:

profit

 

labour

 

Footnote

 

capital

 

borrower

 

Brants

 

employed

 
derive
 

pecunia

 

belongs


character
 

employment

 

profitable

 

teaching

 
contrary
 
partnership
 

Deutschland

 

return

 

amount

 

produce


canonists

 

Therefore

 

sterile

 

Wuchers

 
exaction
 

sinful

 

recompense

 
discussion
 

Neumann

 

exploitation


Gerson

 

central

 

person

 

payment

 

exertion

 

reward

 

belonging

 

Geschichte

 
impossible
 

Bernardine


Sienna

 

simply

 

merchants

 

multiply

 

productive

 

exchange

 

commonly

 

properly

 
capable
 

denying