FREE BOOKS

Author's List




PREV.   NEXT  
|<   317   318   319   320   321   322   323   324   325   326   327   328   329   330   331   332   333   334   335   336   337   338   339   340   341  
342   343   344   345   346   347   348   349   350   351   352   353   354   355   356   357   358   359   360   361   362   363   364   365   366   >>   >|  
ut of the ground and sold, income tax is paid only on the difference between the assigned capital value per unit and the selling profit. If, for instance, the capital value as of March 1, 1913, is placed at 50c. per ton of mineral in the ground, and ten years later a ton is sold for a profit of $1, income tax is paid on 50c. The figure of 50c. per ton as value in the ground is actually obtained by estimating a profit, when the ore is ultimately mined and sold, of $1 per ton, and discounting this dollar to present worth as of March 1, 1913. Therefore the total amounts on which taxes are paid during the life of the mine should represent approximately the total accruals of interest from March 1, 1913. In this manner the proportion of annual income to be taxed becomes larger with the length of the life period. With a deposit having a life of thirty years the net result is that about half of the aggregate income is taxed, though this figure of course varies somewhat with the interest rate used. In the collection of income taxes from coal mines in England, and in the collection of certain state income taxes in the United States, a considerably smaller allowance is made for the retirement of capital value (or for _depletion_, as this is commonly called). In these cases the deduction allowed is a small fixed percentage of the capital value, regardless of the actual life of the property. The treatment of mineral resources as wasting assets in the United States income tax law meets one considerable practical difficulty--namely, that the law really requires physical or _ad valorem_ valuation of every mineral property by the government, as a check on the claims for depletion allowance. This immense and expensive task is too much for the tax collection agencies as now organized, and it may be questionable whether it will ever be desirable to expand these agencies to the extent required for such a purpose. This is the principal argument for the use of arbitrary depletion factors such as those sometimes used abroad. There are many advocates of the straight tonnage tax on mineral deposits, on the ground that it is simple, definite, and easily applied. The present tendency is to extend the application of this form of tax. It is clear, however, that to assume the same value per ton for taxing purposes on a property making a large profit, and on another property which, because of physical conditions, is barely able to operate at a pr
PREV.   NEXT  
|<   317   318   319   320   321   322   323   324   325   326   327   328   329   330   331   332   333   334   335   336   337   338   339   340   341  
342   343   344   345   346   347   348   349   350   351   352   353   354   355   356   357   358   359   360   361   362   363   364   365   366   >>   >|  



Top keywords:

income

 

capital

 
mineral
 

profit

 

property

 
ground
 
collection
 
depletion
 

allowance

 

interest


present
 

physical

 

States

 
figure
 
agencies
 
United
 
organized
 

questionable

 

desirable

 
requires

difficulty

 

considerable

 

practical

 

valorem

 

valuation

 
expensive
 

immense

 

claims

 

government

 

tonnage


assume

 

tendency

 
extend
 

application

 

taxing

 

purposes

 

barely

 
operate
 

conditions

 

making


applied

 

easily

 

arbitrary

 

factors

 

argument

 
principal
 
extent
 

required

 

purpose

 

abroad